US dollar forecast revisions
􀂄 Renewed investor interest
The dollar has begun to dip again on the world’s foreign exchange markets,
drawing the attention of investors. In this note we explore the reasons for the
dollar’s decline and provide revised forecasts.
􀂄 The wrong reasons
Various arguments are put forth to explain the dollar’s weakness. These include
excessive Fed money printing, increased inflation risk, large US budget deficits,
doubts about sustainability of the US recovery, and dollar overvaluation. While
many of these factors might eventually push the dollar lower, none provides a
convincing explanation for dollar weakness in 2009.
􀂄 What’s at work
Instead, dollar weakness reflects declining risk aversion (and hence reduced
demand for US dollar liquidity) and, possibly, increased ‘carry’ activity funded in
dollars. Moreover, growth has surprisingly resurfaced in Europe and Japan ahead
of the US. Finally, investors may be (correctly) anticipating that the decline in the
US trade deficit is over.
􀂄 Revised forecasts
We now forecast year-end 2009 EUR/USD at 1.40 (was 1.30) and 2010 1.50 (was
1.40). The corresponding yen rates are 95 (was 100) and 90 (was 95). We maintain
year-end 2009 and 2010 US dollar forecasts versus the Chinese renminbi of 6.80
and 6.60, respectively
􀂄 Benign dollar decline?
For now, dollar weakness is benign, in our view. It reflects lessening investor risk
aversion. However, imbalances in the world economy remain significant. US
external deficits increasingly reflect large structural fiscal deficits, which if left
unaddressed pose significant medium-term risks for the dollar.
US dollar forecast revisions
In this note we consider the outlook for the US dollar against the euro and the
Japanese yen. The dollar’s direction has become a source of greater investor
interest in recent weeks, given its gradual weakening in the world’s foreign
exchange markets. As a result, the dollar is now significantly weaker than we
had forecasted for year-end 2009 (namely, EUR/USD 1.30 and USD/JPY 100),
prompting the forecast revisions which we outline below.
In what follows, we assess various drivers of the dollar’s external value and how
these are likely to evolve over the coming year. We also consider the risks to our
new dollar forecasts.
What can not explain dollar weakness?
Various cases are offered to explain the dollar’s movements. While all currency
models have a distressing habit of breaking down sooner or later, it is
nevertheless possible to separate plausible reasons for the dollar’s recent dip
from those that don’t add up. We begin with arguments that aren’t persuasive:
􀁑 The Fed is printing too much money. So long as bank lending remains
anaemic, the expansion of the Fed’s balance sheet is having little impact on
the supply of dollars in the broader economy or financial markets, including
the foreign exchange market. To the point, rate of total bank credit growth
continues to decelerate. In short, the Fed has created plenty of ‘high-powered
money’, but it largely sits idle on bank balance sheets and is having little
direct impact on economic activity or most asset prices, including currency
values.
The US is faced with resurgent inflation. Fears of high inflation would be
negative for the dollar. However, near- and long-term inflation expectations
are well-behaved and provide little evidence to suggest that investors are
fretting about price pressures in the US economy.
Investors are worried about US budget deficits. Large budget deficits, if
left unaddressed, would pose significant challenges for the US dollar. But
presumably they would be even more problematic for the US Treasury
market. Yet with bond yields low, it appears that investors are—for now—
not concerned about US government financing risk.
􀁑 The US is in the midst of a ‘false’ recovery. If US growth were expected to
falter, the dollar would probably weaken in the currency markets. Yet if that
were the consensus expectation among investors, equity and credit markets
would also be giving up ground. Their ongoing strength, in contrast, suggests
that growth expectations, per se, are not the source of recent dollar softness.
􀁑 The dollar is overvalued. On our estimates, it is actually the euro that
screens as somewhat overvalued, with a bilateral PPP rate of about
EUR/USD 1.20. The dollar is near fair value against the yen (PPP of
USD/JPY 95.0). The dollar is, in our view, significantly overvalued against
the renminbi. The dollar ought to fall versus the renminbi, but, courtesy of
significant reserve accumulation by the Chinese authorities, is prevented
from doing so.
What can explain dollar weakness?
To be sure, several of the preceding reasons might eventually become sources of
dollar weakness. Ruling them out today does not mean ruling them out
indefinitely. However, we think the drivers of recent dollar weakness lie
elsewhere.
One factor that helps to explain the dollar’s softness this year is the resumption
of more normal risk-seeking behaviour in the capital markets. That observation
is borne out by the correlation between our UBS Risk Indicator and the
EUR/USD exchange rate or, alternatively, the correlation between the dollar’s
value and our measure of the implied equity risk premium.
These relationships require some elaboration. While the dollar has often been
viewed as a ‘safe haven’ currency, its performance over the past year—
strengthening sharply just as the US financial system and economy were on the
verge of imploding—seems odd. However, during the extraordinary stresses of
last autumn, investors prized liquidity above all else. And no currency (or capital
market) can match the liquidity found in the US.
Hence, receding demand for liquidity this year as the financial system has
stabilized helps to explain the dollar’s decline, coincident with the recovery of
markets (falling equity risk premiums) and the normalization of risk indicators.
Yet these relationships may also embed more than just a normalization of risk
appetite. If investors are now genuinely seeking higher returns, the low interest
rate environment provided by the Fed may be contributing to dollar weakness
via ‘carry’. In other words, expectations of low and stable funding costs may be
encouraging some investors to borrow in US dollars to invest in various assets,
including foreign currencies and equities (e.g., emerging equities). In this sense,
‘carry’ is different from the usual interest differential approach to currency
modelling. After all, interest differentials (short- or long-term) do not appear to
explain very well the dollar’s movements against the euro in recent years.
Relative growth rates may also be at work. Earlier this year when we forecasted
year-end 2009 exchange rates of EUR/USD 1.30 and USD/JPY 100, we
anticipated that the dollar would benefit from an earlier recovery of the US
economy. That view, in turn, was predicated on the more convincing monetary,
fiscal, and financial policies adopted over the past year in the US than
elsewhere.
However, that’s not the way things have turned out. Various European countries,
led by Germany, were the first to post positive GDP in Q2. So, too, did Japan.
Meanwhile, the US economy continued to shrink through mid-2009. Partly,
those outcomes have to do with the fact that the inventory liquidation was
nearing completion by mid-year, allowing trade and production to recover. That
rebound has benefitted the more trade-oriented German and Japanese economies
than the US. And for Japan, in particular, China’s recovery has also helped to
lift exports.
Finally, the US dollar may also softening on expectations that the improvement
in the US trade and current account deficits witnessed thus far in the cycle is
now coming to an end. Indeed, last month’s sharp widening of the US
merchandise trade deficit likely marks the turning point for the US external
accounts. Why? Because the US external position was undoubtedly flattered
over the past eighteen months by recession-induced import weakness, as well as
by last year’s sharp fall in energy prices. A collapse of inventories, in particular,
contributed to sharp fall in imports. As the inventory liquidation cycle
concludes, so too will the fall in imports. The implication: A bigger US trade
deficit is on the way. Our US team forecasts a current account deficit (as a
percentage of GDP) of 2.7% this year, rising to 3.0% in 2010.
So, as US growth and final demand now begin to normalize (note the sharp
jump in August US retail sales), imports are likely to pick up again. To be sure,
US export growth will benefit from similar developments overseas. However, a
large initial trade deficit (meaning exports must grow faster than imports to
close the gap) and a higher propensity of the US to import than in its trading
partners suggests the return to ever-widening US trade and current account
deficits over the next few years.==========================
当然我个人觉得,做的一般。如果想看全文或者想了解整个脉络,可以给我发短信,留下邮箱。
|